Μετάβαση στο κύριο περιεχόμενο

Reassessment of the OCA Criteria in the Euro Area: The Case of Greece


Abstract

The Greek crisis should not be considered an unexpected phenomenon. On the contrary, it has been caused by, among other things, rushed political decisions, incomplete EU institutions of governance and hidden political and economic causes. We analyze the optimality and effectiveness of the European monetary framework on two different levels, first by applying the OCA criteria to the EMU. Second, by evaluating the main political and economic institutions and their vulnerabilities within the European level. We claim that many European countries, including Greece and other countries of Southern Europe remain unable to afford the vulnerable and one-sided, weak political and economic European monetary context. Additionally, we claim that unless deep governance structures emerge, a possible enlargement of the eurozone could create more costs than benefits for both the candidate members and the Eurozone itself.

JEL Code: G01, F50

Key words: Political Economy, Optimal Currency Areas, Greek crisis, EMU, European Governance

Introduction

In 1991, the Maastricht Treaty was signed by all the European member states. The unique project marked the end of long road efforts to establish the European Monetary Union (EMU). From its early beginning the EMU was a result of intergovernmental bargaining by the most powerful European countries in order to overcome global, regional and national challenges (Moravcsik, 1998; Hosli 2000).  However, twenty years later, the Greek crisis revealed that the EMU’s framework is a complex political and economic environment in which many peripheral European economies remain vulnerable to the political and economic shocks that can happen on a regular basis mainly because of conflicted national interests and preferences at the European level. In this regard, De Grauwe (2010e, p.172) argues that ‘large areas of economic policies remain in the hand of national governments creating asymmetric shocks that undermine the sustainability of the monetary union’. Thus, the weak European politico-economic institutional context, in which the current Greek crisis was developed, has also contributed to the current crisis.
The effectiveness of the European monetary framework can be better analyzed through the application of the optimal currency areas (OCA) criteria as it was first developed by Mundell (1961) and later by McKinnon (1963), and Kennen (1969) together with the evaluation of vulnerabilities of the main political and economic institutions. The economic and political integration and convergence of Greece within the Eurozone has never been satisfactory or real. In fact, Baldwin (2001) believes that Luxemburg was the only country which fulfilled all the Maastricht criteria for membership. Thus, the Greek membership within the European Union was, from its beginning, a rushed political decision. This context, together with the Greek political and economic structural deficiencies (Sklias and Galatsidas, 2010) and the continuous neglect of the EMU’s norms (Kosters, 2010a) creates an explosive mixture of conditions that in the long run will have a negative impact on both regionally and globally. As Wyplosz (2006, p.220) stated ‘If Europe is not an OCA and yet decides to create a common currency, there will be economic costs. If these costs are high and the political criteria are not met, the undertaking will fail’. As a result, in order to assess the long-run sustainability of the Eurozone we need to focus on both the political and economic conditions that led to its existence. 
Thus, this paper intends to analyze the European political and economic context in which the Greek crisis was developed. As it will be argued many European countries, including Greece and other countries of Southern Europe remain unable to afford the vulnerable and one-sided, weak political and economic European monetary context within which they lose important elements of their political and economic sovereignty. Thus, as long as these countries remain unable to afford the economic competition within the Eurozone and as no structural improvement can be observed within the whole system of the European economic governance, then the European monetary framework is potentially transformed to a political and economic trap. This trap was developed because in fact the European area is not an optimal currency area and many European countries joined the European Union politically. This omission is also responsible for the current crisis together with the neglect of the European political leaders to create a sustainable system of the European economic governance because of their national interests. Moreover, unless deep governance structures emerge, a possible enlargement of the Eurozone could create more costs than benefits for both the candidate members and the Eurozone itself. Under these conditions the EU will remain unstable in the long run.
First, we apply the first three OCA economy-related criteria for the case of Greece, those being labor mobility, production diversification, and openness. Second, we assess the remaining three criteria, namely, the homogeneous preferences, the fiscal transfers and the solidarity which are related not only to the level of European economic performance but also to political and institutional vulnerabilities that can be observed at the European level.  In this framework we also assess whether the European Central Bank (ECB) or the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) are as effective as the European member states need. Then, we argue that the possibility of future crises will be increased, especially when the NMS join the EMU. Finally, we make specific recommendations for future thought and consideration, focusing on the European economic governance structure.

The Application of the OCA Criteria to the EMU.

The OCA theory is an adequate means for assessment of the European monetary project. However, its significance affected neither the Maastricht Treaty nor the formation of convergence criteria. The Maastricht Treaty was affected only by a few and, as it proved later, controversial publications like the Delors Report. The policy makers and politicians omitted the fact that Europe is not a perfect OCA, contrary to what many important studies for example Eichengreen (1991) and Bayoumi and Eichengreen  (1992) had argued, and thus the creation of a solid European economic and political architecture failed. Consequently, the whole European economic governance was limited by some inefficient and insufficient economic and political institutions and policy goals. Such failures and omissions are responsible for today’s European governance problems.
For the application of the OCA Baldwin and Wyplosz (2006) propose six criteria in order to answer the question of whether one country is able or unable to participate in a monetary union. These criteria can either be based on economic factors like labour mobility, production diversification, and openness or on semi-economic semi-political elements like the possibility of fiscal transfers, homogeneous preferences and the solidarity criterion. According to them, European countries do not satisfy either the labour mobility or the fiscal transfer criterion, they only partly satisfy the homogeneity of preferences criterion and it is very unclear whether there exists a common sense of solidarity. Instead, the European countries satisfy the trade openness and the production diversification criteria. However, a closer look at the data reminds us that Greece was an exception.
However, one could ask if is it too early to assess whether the Eurozone fails to determine the OCA (Wyplosz, 2006). The European economic crisis which started in Greece nearly 3 years ago is a sign of a negative answer to the question. Within the EMU there exist major economic divergencies on Gross Domestic Product (GDP), employment, labour productivity, budget deficits and debt. The partial fulfillment of the OCA criteria and the partial integration prescribed to a large extent the fact that the participation within the EMU could create many disadvantages and costs for the majority of European countries as the process of the monetary unification was a political project based on national preferences and interests.
It is now obvious that many critical elements of OCA theory was disregarded by many European political leaders. The first critical issue which is related to Mundell’s OCA theory is the incidence of asymmetric shocks which are directly related to labour mobility and wage rigidities. According to the OCA framework many argued that the United States (US) is in a much better position than the European Union to form a monetary union because its regions can adapt to asymmetric shocks better than the EU’s regions and, in fact, labour mobility at the European level is lower than that in the US (Eichengreen, 1990; Bayoumi and Eichengreen, 1992). Barry Eichengreen (1990b) also argued that within the U.S. there is a faster labour market adjustment than within the Euro area. This suggests that when an asymmetric shock, either supply or demand, happens within the Euro area the member states are unable to act against this shock because of such a lack in labour mobility. Thus, because of the low level of labour mobility and existence of major wage rigidities within the Eurozone there are substantial limits on the EU’s ability to absorb the negative supply and demand shocks (Dibooglu and Horvath, 1997).
The current global financial and economic crisis that started in the US in 2007 proved that peripheral European countries are not only affected by very different economic shocks, but in contrast to the core countries, they have less ability to surpass these negative shocks because of major flaws in the European economic architecture. Within the Eurozone there is no official and effective mechanism to compensate the negative shocks. Thus, Greece, was unable theoretically and empirically to manage the economic shocks.
Applying the first OCA criterion to the Greek case Table 1 shows the existence of substantial asymmetries in supply and demand shocks. In conjunction with the fact that within the Eurozone labour mobility and wage flexibility are not of an adequate level (Fink and Salvatore, 1999) the members cannot respond effectively to major economic disturbances. As it had been argued ‘Greece and Italy in 2003 had the last two degrees in labour force participation within the Eurozone’ (Angeloni, Flad, and Mongelli, 2007, p.383). Many of the NMS had better degrees of labour force participation. This implies that important factors remain immobile even within the Greek region and the asymmetric costs for many peripheral countries are much higher than the core European countries. For example, Wyplosz (2006, p.220) stated that ‘Greece is the only country found to have undergone asymmetric shocks for all three variables’ (GDP growth, inflation,  and unemployment).

 Table 1. Correlation Coefficients of Supply and Demand Shocks in Germany with Other European Countries

Supply Shocks
Demand Shocks
Germany
1
1
France
0,54
0,35
Belgium
0,61
0,33
Netherlands
0,59
0,17
Denmark
0,59
0,39
United Kingdom
0,11
0,16
Italy
0,23
0,17
Spain
0,31
-0,07
Ireland
-0,06
-0,08
Portugal
0,21
0,21
Greece
0,14
0,19
Source: Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1992).

In this regard, Greece is much less equipped to overcome these asymmetric shocks than Germany because of the subjective and objective costs of moving away, the cultural differences and the differences in language compared to the other European countries which are huge. Even though the existence of significant shocks and asymmetries within the Eurozone are uncontested as well as the labour mobility and wage flexibility is lower than the US, no economic and political tool has been developed at the European level in order to overcome these flaws. As a result, for Greece and other peripheral countries the asymmetric and idiosyncratic disturbances within the Eurozone, together with the presence of labour immobility and wage rigidities, but also with the loss of any monetary policy tool make the participation a serious challenge for the country itself.
Second, following Kenen’s production diversification criterion we assume that an OCA should be created only when the member states have a well diversified level of production and exports.  Does Greece fulfill the production diversification criterion? According to the trade dissimilarity index, it is clear that there are significant differences in terms of the effect of trade on monetary integration (Baldwin and Wyplosz, 2006). A more critical examination shows that Greece is second, behind Norway, in terms of the dissimilarity score, its economy is not as integrated with the European economy. Thus, even though there are many members that are very enthusiastic to participate in the EMU because of their economic interests, the Greek score implies that the EMU could have a negative impact on Greece. As a result, the EMU has not been advantageous for the Greece.
Third, what happened to the openness within the Eurozone? Is Greece an open enough economy? The majority of the members of the EMU seem to fulfill the openness criterion as they have demonstrated an increased average in ratios of exports and imports to GDP and larger pass-through coefficients at the same time. However, again Greece seems to be an exception. According to the Statistical Annex of European Economy (2005), Greece has the lowest average of exports and imports in relation to GDP with 25.5%. In contrast, Italy’s average is 27.9%, Portugal’s average is 36.2%, Bulgaria’s average is 65.9% and Turkey’s average is 36.5%. As a result, it can also be argued that in terms of openness Greece was unable to participate in the EMU. Again this fact was overlooked, not only by Greece, but also by the European political leaders.
The aforementioned discussion makes it evident that within the EMU there are significant differences between the countries as to what concerns the application of the first three OCA criteria that directly affect each country’s ability to overcome external shocks. In the case of Greece, the data demonstrate an adverse tendency, weakening the sustainable long term participation of the country in the Eurozone.

Institutional, Political and Economic Vulnerabilities

The OCA theory provides three more criteria for the evaluation of each country’s ability to participate in a currency union. However, the last three criteria namely, homogeneous preferences, fiscal transfers and solidarity are not related only to the European economic performance but also with political and institutional vulnerabilities that can be observed at the European level. As it will also be stated the political and institutional weaknesses at the European level affect the performance of the EMU’s member states and mainly the performance of the peripheral countries. In this regard, Greece stands alone within the European community when an economic shock directly or indirectly affects its performance.
First, the homogeneity of preferences criterion states that, any time a crisis arises, a monetary union should propose common actions on how to solve the crisis. But, do the European states share the same preferences or at least the same priorities in order to solve the problems and shocks that frequently arise within the EMU? The current crisis and especially the Greek case proved that within the EMU there is no common consensus on how to deal with crises. For the last two years the European countries have tried to compensate the negative effects of the global financial crisis on an individual basis where national preferences and interests prevail. Moreover, it is clear that Greece needs a very special monetary and fiscal policy that within the EMU is regarded as a utopia. Greece is unable to take any monetary decision and after the IMF’s intervention cannot even use its fiscal policy. Furthermore, even within the monetary field Greece and Portugal have very little in common with Germany and France. The great divergencies in the GDP, current account deficits and public debts, and inflation rates between the core European countries and the peripheral countries have caused an explosive political and economic environment within EMU.
The European context has also been transformed into a trap because of the function of its main economic institution. The ECB has been developed in order to serve as a monetary union with a rather limited sense of solidarity. Furthermore, anytime the ECB’s Executive Board follows the method of ‘one member, one vote’ and the economic cycles among the countries are unequally allocated then severe conflicts and crises can arise (Bindseil, 2001). For example, when a sudden economic shock occurs within the Eurozone, the effectiveness of the ECB is decreased. In addition, the “one-size-fits-all” monetary policy of the ECB could worsen the macroeconomic performance of many European countries like Greece. As a result, there are many flaws and deficiencies that affect the operational capacity of the ECB and pose a substantial risk to Euroland’s survival (Buiter, 1999). In this context, the majority of the peripheral countries cannot remain competitive within the Eurozone.
On the other hand, the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) which was adopted as one of the main institutional projects for stability and growth within the Eurozone in order to overcome the limits of the fiscal autonomy of the member states and to stop the ‘free riders’(Horstmann and Schneider, 1994)  seems very weak. First, its weak institutional foundation is related to the lack of accountability of the Commission (De Grauwe, 2010e). As McNamara (2005, p.156) argues ‘although the SGP has the word growth in its title, it is not likely to promote growth, but rather to be excessively restrictive’. In this respect, not only many countries like Greece have no incentive to comply with the pre-agreed rules, but also it seems that at the same time these countries have been trapped under the vulnerable institutional guidelines of the SGP, which undermines the sustainability of the Eurozone. As one can observe from Figure 1. eleven of the sixteen European countries failed to fulfill the Maastricht criterion for at least one year out of the last three.


Figure 1. Public Debt within the EU


The most important weakness of the SGP is derived from the political elements of the Excessive Deficit Procedure which was first suspended from France and Germany (Leblond, 2006; Heipertz and Verdun, 2004). Moreover, as Kosters (2010b, p.341) states ‘The acceptance of Greece into the EMU in 2001 on the basis of false budget figures, and the fact that it failed to comply with the budget criteria in every single year after its admission without being sanctioned, confirmed that the examination of adherence was too lax’. With regards to Greece’s inclusion in the Eurozone, Leblond (2006, p.986) believes that ‘It was always considered a political animal more than an economic one’. As Stark (2001) argues ‘political authorities in many member states were unaware or only vaguely aware that the signing of the Maastricht Treaty, with its requirement that excessive deficits be avoided, has limited national sovereignty in the area of fiscal policy’.
Finally, there is not only a lack of a mechanism for fiscal transfers but also a coordination mechanism between fiscal and monetary policies. The EU needs an economic institution that could organize not only the monetary but also the budgetary and fiscal policies in the Eurozone. Jovanovic (2005, p.60) states that the EU ‘unlike in the US, there is no fiscal element in the deal. Automatic fiscal transfers as built-in stabilisers do not exist’. On the other hand, there is a strong political unwillingness from many European countries to prevent the possibility of a coordination mechanism. Thus, “the one size fits all” monetary policy that cannot accommodate regional variations and lacks adequate mechanism for fiscal transfers will impede rather than promote efficient operation of the internal market’ (Gillingham, 2003, p.269). According to De Grauwe (2010c, p.3) ‘this imbalance leads to creeping divergencies between member states and there is no mechanism to correct or to alleviate them’.
The aforementioned deficiencies are important elements of the European complexities. As long as Germany and other core European countries are able to follow their own economic policies then not only will the economic divergencies within the Euro area continue to exist but also that many peripheral countries will remain, unable to resist, trapped within the euro area.
As Feldstein (1997, p.41) argued ‘Political leaders in Europe seem prepared to ignore these adverse consequences (…) though such a policy is often advocated as a way to reduce conflict within Europe, it may well have the opposite effect’. This behaviour can only be explained in the name of national preferences and interests. Theoretically, is explained through Moravcsik’s liberal intergovernmentalism (Moravcsik, 1993) and more specifically through the revised embedded intergovernmentalism in which the concerns of the stronger nation states within the Eurozone are affected by their powerful socio-economic actors (Talani, 2005; Talani, 2007; Talani, 2008). As Talani (2007, p.299) argues ‘Intergovernmentalist would predict that the interest of the most powerful member states prevail over the one of smaller states’. Thus, it is not extreme to argue that conflicts of interest can be observed among the most powerful European states the last two decades (Tombazos, 2011). As a result, the weak member states seem to be trapped by national business preferences that can modify policy decisions already agreed at the European level (Crouch, 2002).  .
Eventually, we can argue that:

1. A small peripheral country like Greece is unable to use most of the economic and political tools that have been developed in the European context aiming at overcoming many of the regular or sudden economic and political socks within the Eurozone
2. Such countries did not initially fulfill the set criteria for participation in the EMU. In this respect, it seems that Greece entered into the European context without the qualifications required. Eventually, Greece entered into a vicious cycle without the necessary qualifications of eligibility.  
3. Within the EMU the political and economic environment is more violent and conflicted than harmonious, although this is very difficult to be observed. Weak economies such as Greece are exposed to both internal and external shocks.
4. The politico-economic European governance framework is insufficient with many flaws and deficiencies.
5. No political-will, leadership can be identified sufficient to overcome the governance deficiencies.

The Case of the New Member States

The Greek crisis has been analysed as a phenomenon that was caused by rushed political decisions, incomplete institutions of governance, and hidden political and economic causes within the EMU. However, if this is the situation what does the case of the NMS tell us? Several studies have been developed in order to assess whether the NMS are able to participate in the EMU. The majority of these studies have concluded that their performance is at best as good as the peripheral countries (Fidrmuc and Korhonen, 2006) But, if this is the best and most optimistic scenario then we should be very concerned.
Horvath and Ratfai (2004) claim that the supply socks remain uncorrelated among Germany, France, and Italy on the one side and Czech Republic, Slovakia, Poland, Hungary, Slovenia, Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania. Moreover, Fidrmuc and Korhonen (2003) argued that there are many prospective countries with great asymmetries in business cycles. According to them only Hungary and Estonia are able to participate in the EMU without substantial and detrimental costs. Darvas and Szapary (2008) argued that not only are there substantial differences in the degree of correlation but also, in fact, these divergencies change with time creating huge gaps. In a more recent study, Mikek (2009) argued that the symmetry of shocks of both supply and demand among the old and the new member states should not be taken for granted. All the above studies conclude that the shocks for the majority of the NMS are asymmetric. A possible enlargement of the Eurozone could create in the long run more costs and problems than benefits not only for the NMS but also for the Eurozone as a whole.
Under the aforementioned analysis, one should be more critical in the question of whether a prospect enlargement will have positive effects both for the prospect countries and for the Eurozone. The Greek crisis and the majority of studies the last 20 years show that participation within the EMU is not as simple as it looks. The one-sided political decisions for membership should be avoided. The theoretical studies should influence more of the European political and economic decisions and policy making. The European context has been transformed to a big and unseen trap for the majority of the European countries which has to be taken into consideration for future enlargements. We have few reasons to believe that the new member states, the candidates and potential candidates’ countries are really different than Greece or at least if they are more capable to survive within the EMU context. Do not forget that they will loose any monetary instrument directly; they will not be able to use the money supply, exchange rate or interest rate as important policy tools. Furthermore, their fiscal policies do not ensure their success. Take for example the Greek, the Spanish, and the Portuguese cases. In addition, within the EMU the comparative advantage is transformed to an absolute advantage with huge negative consequences not only for the trade, but also for their competitiveness, exports, and growth. We have few reasons to believe that the case for the NMS is really any different. Thus, these countries do not in reality have any mechanisms to fight the asymmetries within the Eurozone. In the long run these countries will face the same problems that now Portugal, Spain and Greece have faced.


What needs to be done?

It is ironic but true, that many scholars proposed solutions for the problems of the European economic governance and it is even more ironic that none of these have been transformed into policy measures. Even today, the recently agreed solution for the Greek debt situation is not a solution at all. In contrast to the optimistic public statements, the agreement does not provide an adequate framework for solving the structural weaknesses of the Eurozone. This is because of the calculated political and economic costs for the core European countries. This means that the Eurozone will continue to trap its weaker members in a shadow and unsustainable political and economic environment.  This is because a) it is a solution only for the Greek case, b) no improvements of the Eurozone’s structural economic and political governance problems can be observed c) the European leaders also failed to see that the European economic crisis calls for better coordination within the structures of European economic governance at the political and economic level. The Greek economic crisis is only a sign of how all these hidden and non-hidden economic, political and institutional characteristics affect the stability and development in Europe. But, what needs to be done?

  1. Effective Institutions

In 1991, Barry Eichengreen (1991, p.3)  wrote:

‘the establishment of a currency union in Europe will be associated with non-negligible regional problems. This makes it all the more essential to develop the political and economic institutions necessary for the smooth operation of a currency union […] the absence of comparable institutions in Europe is a serious challenge to the case for an OCA turns out to be a complicated question’.

Unfortunately, none of the established political and economic institutions contributed to the overall stability of the Eurozone. As we have already analyzed even the ECB with its “one size fits all” policy creates several problems because not all the countries are able to follow their decisions especially because significant asymmetries lie within the Eurozone. The creation of more effective political and economic institutions in order to improve the European economic and political governance is a necessity.

  1. Alternative Adjustment Mechanism

Moreover, Eichengreen (1991) proposed a system of budgetary transfers, a possible injection of liquidity from other countries. This calls for a system of redistributive policies which also requires a central fiscal authority (Dibooglu and Horvath, 1997). There is a need for an economic institution that could organize not only the monetary but also the budgetary and fiscal policies in the Eurozone (Verdun, 2007). It is obvious that not only can no European representative for fiscal policies be found (Dominguez, 2006) but also it is clear that within the Eurozone no redistributive system exists in order to compensate for the negative asymmetries (De Grauwe, 2009a). Thus, the creation of an alternative adjustment mechanism in order to compensate for the negative asymmetric failures within the Eurozone is also being necessary.


  1. The European Monetary Fund and the  Common Euro-bond Market

The European Monetary Fund (EMF) and the Common Euro-bond Market are two more important solutions for the problems within the Eurozone (Gros and Mayer, 2010a; Gros and Mayer, 2010b; Gros and Micossi, 2008; De Grauwe and Moesen, 2009). One more step could also be the creation of a ‘clear framework to deal with the consequences of a member country’s failure to abide by the fundamental rules’ (Gros, 2010, p. 2).

  1. Political Union

Under certain circumstances, a political union as a final outcome within the EMU is the most highly desirable outcome because the lack of a concurring political union is the most severe deficiency within the Eurozone (De Grauwe, 2006; De Grauwe, 2008; De Grauwe, 2009b).  The political union not only makes the membership less costly but also reduces the asymmetries that emanate from political conflicts (De Grauwe, 2009a). Thus, its absence is regarded as a major failure. However, the EMU has few possibilities to construct an ever closer political union. One of the main reasons for this is that the citizens of the EU do not seem to share a feeling of mutual perspective that surpasses many of the nationalist propensities. The other is the political unwillingness to do it. As Dominguez (2006, p.68)  observes ‘European economic integration is built on a group of countries each of which wants to stay largely as it was before integration (…) many citizens in Europe are still grappling with the question of how truly unified they care to be’.  As a result, it is clear that there is an absence of the ‘deep variable’ (De Grauwe, 2009b) that is highly related with the solidarity criterion. As De Grauwe (2006, p.723)  states ‘A union in which member states show zero solidarity for the plight of other states cannot hope to have a reasonable chance of survival’.


Conclusion

According to the analysis above it is not as obvious as to whether the rules and principles within the EMU are concrete and can create a solid background for viable economic and financial policies. The EMU from its early beginning was based not on each country’s ability to participate but on political reasons. Political and economic priorities have considerably overcome economic and fiscal principles in the formation and function of the EMU. However, it is obvious that the rules of the game are not viable anymore. Greece and other peripheral countries cannot afford to remain in a European context full of deficiencies, flaws and inequalities. Either as a matter of economic or political necessity a great transformation to the system of the European economic governance has to occur in the near future. 
            More specifically, this paper argues that the EMU’s political, economic and institutional context seems to be a rather complicated framework for certain member states of the EMU like Greece, Portugal, Spain and Ireland, namely the “weak” or ‘‘peripheral’’ economies. In this regard, there are some important observations:
1. The political leaders omitted several theoretical and empirical studies related to some shocking aspects of the European unification. A rushed system of political and economic governance was created. This system cannot assist member states to address asymmetric shocks.
2.  The production factors remain immobile and the wages rigid. This does not help with the appeasement of asymmetric shocks. Certain member states, including Greece do not fulfil the production diversification and the openness criteria, a fact that was also omitted. Considering that the criterion of homogeneity of preferences within the Eurozone is only partly satisfied, the weak peripheral countries remain unable to be competitive and to overcome the economic and political challenges within the Eurozone.
3. The ECB is not as efficient as it could be and its one size fits all monetary policy creates several problems for the peripheral countries with special needs. SGP does not provide an adequate mechanism for growth at all.
4. But the most important of all is the lack of solidarity.  As Dyson and Featherstone (1999, p.796) stated ‘EMU’s Achilles heel was the prospect of people being asked to make sacrifices for others with whom there was a weak sense of solidarity’.
The above observations create increased anxieties for prospective enlargements because the Maastricht criteria are not an adequate sign of the state’s ability to cope with several problems and to remain competitive within the Eurozone. It is a considerable concern that even in the midst of the major economic crisis the so called Greek solution does not provide an adequate framework for tackling the root causes of the problem.
            It is now obvious that economically weak European states remain trapped within the Eurozone both economically and politically. The economic reasons create disastrous unseen conditions that negatively affect the economic performance of the peripheral European countries. On the other hand, the political and institutional context does not help these countries to overcome their challenges at all and also no real improvement of this framework can be observed even in the middle of the great European economic crisis. Greece cannot use any monetary policy tool and because of its huge public deficits and debts and the memorandum with the IMF, it cannot use any fiscal policy tool to increase its growth. How can anyone expect this country to overcome the economic and political coma?  So as long as the European political and economic context remains as weak as it is, many European countries will be unable to overcome their challenges. As long as the political leaders do not intervene in the aforementioned political and economic context by taking important decisions for its improvement, the pessimistic prospect prevails and the Eurozone remains unsustainable.


Bibliographical References

Angeloni, I. Flad, M and Mongelli, F.P. (2007) ‘Monetary Integration of the New EU Member States: What Sets the Pace of Euro Adoption?’, Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 45 No. 2, pp.367-409.
Baldwin, R. (2001) ‘On the Microeconomics of the European Monetary Union’, European Economy, Special Edition, No. 1, pp.19-35.
Baldwin, R and Wyplosz, C. (2006) ‘The Economics of European Integration’, McGraw-Hill Education, Berkshire.
Bayoumi, T and Eichengreen, B. (1992) ‘Shocking Aspects of European Monetary Unification’, NBER Working Paper No. 3949, Cambridge.
Bindseil, U. (2001) ‘A Coalition-Form Analysis of the ‘One Country-One Vote’ Rule in the Governing Council of the European Central Bank’, International Economic Journal, Vol. 15 No. 1, pp.141-164.
Buiter, W. H. (1999) ‘Alice in Euroland’, CEPR Policy Paper,  No. 1, pp.1-36.
Crouch, C. (2002) ‘The Euro and Labour Markets and Wage Policies’, in Dyson, K., (eds) European States and the Euro. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp.278-305.
Darvas, Z and Szapary, G. (2008) ‘Bussiness Cycle Synchronization in the Enlarged EU’, Open Economies Review, Vol. 19 No. 1, pp.1-19.
De Grauwe, P. (2006) ‘What have we Learnt about Monetary Integration since the Maastricht Treaty?’, Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 44 No. 4, pp.711-730.
De Grauwe, P. (2008) ‘Review: On the Need to Renovate the Eurozone’, International Finance, Vol. 11 No. 3, pp.327-333.
De Grauwe, P. (2009a) ‘Some Thoughts on Monetary and Political Union’, in Talani, S., L., (Eds) The Future of EMU. Palgrave MacMillan, New York, pp.9-28.
De Grauwe, P. (2009b) ‘The Euro at Ten: Achievements and Challenges’, Empirica, Vol. 36 No.1, pp.5-20.
De Grauwe, P. (2010c) ‘Crisis in the Eurozone and How to Deal with it’, Centre for European Policy Studies, CEPS Policy Brief, No. 204, February.
De Grauwe, P. (2010e) ‘The Fragility of the Eurozone’s Institutions’, Open Economies Review, Vol. 21 No.1, pp.167-174.
De Grauwe, P and Moesen, W. (2009) ‘Gains for All: A Proposal for a Common Euro Bond’, Intereconomics, Vol. 44 No. 3, pp.132-141.
Dibooglu, S and Horvath, J. (1997) ‘Optimum Currency Areas and the European Monetary Unification’, Contemporary Economic Policy, Vol. 15 No. 1, pp.37-49.
Dominguez, K. (2006) ‘The European Central Bank, the Euro, and Global Financial Markets’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 20, No.4, pp.67-88.
Dyson, K and Featherstone, K. (1999) ‘The Road to Maastricht: Negotiating Economic and Monetary Union’, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Eichengreen, B. (1990) ‘Costs and Benefits of European Monetary Unification’, Centre for Economic Policy Research, Discussion Paper No. 453, London.
Eichengreen, B. (1990b) ‘One Money for Europe? Lessons from the U.S. Currency Union’. Economic Policy, Vol. 5 No. 10, pp.117-187.
Eichengreen, B. (1991) ‘Is Europe an Optimum Currency Area?’, NBER Working Paper, No. 3579, Cambridge.
European Central Bank, (2010) ‘Euro Area Fiscal Policies and the Crisis’, Eurosystem, Occasional Paper Series, No. 109.
European Economy, (2005) ‘Statistical Annex of European Economy’, Directorate General Economic and Financial Affairs, Spring.
Feldstein, M. (1997) ‘The Political Economy of the European Economic and Monetary Union: Political Sources of and Economic Liability’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 11 No. 4, pp.23-42.
Fidrmuc, J and Korhonen, L. (2003) ‘Similarity of Supply and Demand Schocks between the Euro Area and the CEECs’, Economic Systems, pp.313-334.
Fidrmuc J and Korhonen, L. (2006) ‘Meta analysis of the Bussines Cycle Correlation between the Euro Area and the CEEC’s’, Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 34 No. 3, pp.518-537.
Fink, G and Salvatore, D. (1999) ‘Benefits and Costs of European Economic and Monetary Union’, The Brown Journal of World Affairs, Vol. 6 No. 2, pp.187-194.
Gillingham, J. (2003) ‘European Integration 1950-2003: Superstate or New Market Economy?’, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Gros, D. (2010) ‘Is Financial Failure an Option in the EU?’, Centre for European Policy Studies, CEPS Commentary.
Gros, D and Mayer, T. (2010a) ‘Financial Stability beyond Greece: Making the most of the European Stabilisation Mechanism’, Centre for European Policy Studies,  CEPS Commentary.
Gros, D and Mayer, T. (2010b) How to deal with Sovereign Default in Europe: Create the European Monetary Fund now!’, Centre for European Policy Studies, CEPS Policy Brief, No. 202.
Gros, D and Micossi, S. (2008) ‘A Call for a European Financial Stability Fund’, Centre for European Policy Studies, CEPS Commentaries.
Heipertz, M and Verdun, A. (2004) ‘The Dog that would Never Bite? What we can Learn from the Origins of the Stability and Growth Pact’, Journal of European Public Policy, Vol. 11 No. 5, pp.765-780.
Horstmann, W and Schneider, F. (1994) ‘Deficits, Bailout and Free Riders: Fiscal Elements of a European Constitution’,  Kyklos, Vol. 47 No. 3, pp.355-383.
Hosli, O. (2000) ‘The Creation of the European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU): Intergovernmental Negotiations and Two-Level Games’, Journal of European Public Policy, Vol. 7 No. 5, pp.744-766. 
Horvath, J and Ratfai, A. (2004) ‘Supply and Demand Shocks in Accession Countries to the Economic and Monetary Union’, Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 32 No. 2, pp. 202-211.
Jovanovic, M. (2005) ‘The Economics of the European Integration: Limits and Prospects’, Edward Elgar, Massachusetts.
Kenen, P. (1969) ‘The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas’, in Mundell, R. and Swoboda, A. (Eds) Monetary Problems of the International Economy, Chicago University Press, Chicago.
Kosters, W. (2010a) ‘Challenges Facing European Monetary Union – Rules and Assignment or Discretion and Coordinatiion?’, Intereconomics, Vol. 45 No. 2, pp.86-89.
Kosters, W. (2010b) ‘Credible Rules, Not Discretion, Will Make the Euro Sustainable’, in Intereconomics Forum (Eds), Eight Months Later – Has the Eurozone Been Stabilised or Will EMU Fall Apart? Intereconomics, Vol. 45 No. 6, pp.340-356.
Leblond, P. (2006) ‘The Political Stability and Growth Pact is Dead: Long Live the Economic Stability and Growth Pact’, Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 44 No. 5, pp.969-990.
McKinnon, R. (1963) ‘Optimum Currency Areas’, American Economic Review, Vol. 53 No. 4, pp.717-725.
McNamara, K. R. (2005) ‘Economic and Monetary Union: Innovation and Challenges for the Euro’, in Wallace, H., Wallace, W and Pollack, M. (Eds). Policy-Making in the European Union, Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp.141-160.
Mikek, P. (2009) ‘Shocks to New and Old Europe. How Symmetric?’, Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 47 No. 4, pp.811-830.
Moravcsik, A. (1993) ‘Preferences and Power in the European Community: A Liberal Intergovernmentalist Approach’, Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 31 No. 4, pp.473-524.
Moravcsik, A. (1998) ‘The Choice for Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht’, Cornell University Press, Ithaca.
Mundell, R. (1961) ‘A Theory of Optimal Currency Areas’, American Economic Review, Vol. 51 No. 4, pp.657-665.
Sklias P and Galatsidas G. (2010) ‘The political economy of the Greek crisis: roots, causes and perspectives for sustainable development’, Middle Eastern Finance and Economics, Vol. 7, pp.166-177.  
Stark, J. (2001) ‘Genesis of a Pact’, in Brunila, A. Buti, M. and Franco, D. (Eds), The Stability and Growth Pact, Palgrave, London, pp.77-105.
Talani, S. (2005) ‘The European Central Bank: Between Growth and Stability’, Comparative European Politics, Vol. 3 No. 2, pp.204-231.
Talani, S. (2007) ‘The Future of EMU: Towards the Disruption of the European Integration Process’, in Stivachtis, Y. (Eds) The State of European Integration, Ashgate, Hampshire, pp.279-306.
Talani, S. (2008) ‘A Dead Stability and Growth Pact and a Strong Euro: There Must be a Mistake’, in Talani, S and Casey, B. (Eds) Between Growth and Stability: The Demise Reform of the European’s Union Stability and Growth Pact, Edward Elgar Publishing, Massachusetts, pp.85-108.
Tombazos, S. (2011) ‘Centrifugal Tendencies in the Euro Area’, Journal of Contemporary European Studies, Vol. 19 No. 1, pp.33-46.
Verdun, A. (2007) ‘Economic and Monetary Union’, in Cini, M. (Eds) European Union Politics, Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp.324-339.
Wyplosz, C. (2006) ‘European Monetary Union: The Dark Sides of a Major Success’, Economic Policy, Vol. 21 No. 46, pp.207-261.  

Figure 1. Public Debt within the EU
Source: European Central Bank (2010). 

Σχόλια

Δημοφιλείς αναρτήσεις από αυτό το ιστολόγιο

Η ελληνική οικονομική κρίση και τρόποι αντιμετώπισης της.

Είναι προφανές ότι σήμερα ζούμε όχι μέσα σε ένα μονοπολικό, ή διπολικό ή πολυπολικό παγκόσμιο σύστημα αλλά μέσα σε ένα περιβάλλον όπου, κυρίως στον χρηματοοικονομικό τομέα, υπάρχει μια μοναδική άμεση αλληλεπίδραση εντατικότατα και αλληλεξάρτηση. Πολλοί έχουν υποστηρίξει ότι οι κυριότερες αιτίες της τελευταίας διεθνούς οικονομικής κρίσης είναι η έλλειψη συνεργασίας μεταξύ των κρατών, η έλλειψη παγκόσμιων ρυθμιστικών πλαισίων, αρχών και οργάνων καθώς και η μεγάλη οικονομική ανισότητα που παρατηρείται μεταξύ του αναπτυσσόμενου και του ανεπτυγμένου κόσμου. Πολλά θα μπορούσαν να ειπωθούν για τα εγγενή μειονεκτήματα-χαρακτηριστικά του σημερινού παγκόσμιου καπιταλιστικού χρηματοοικονομικού συστήματος όμως δεν θα γίνουν μέρος αυτής της εργασίας. Όπως δεν θα γίνει λόγος για τον ρόλο της Ευρωπαϊκής Ένωσης και των διεθνών σχέσεων για την έξοδο από την κρίση. Αντί αυτού θα προσπαθήσουμε να δείξουμε κάτω από ποιες συνθήκες η ελληνική πολιτική μπορεί να ξεπεράσει την δυσμενή οικονομική θέση που βρίσ

Η κρίση της Ελληνικής πολιτείας

Σε προηγούμενα άρθρα μου σε αυτόν εδώ τον χώρο είχα τονίσει πως η Ελληνική πολιτεία σήμερα όσο ποτέ άλλοτε στο παρελθόν είναι διχασμένη. Εξαιτίας όλων αυτών των διαδικασιών-μετασχηματισμών που συμβαίνουν στο εγχώριο, ευρωπαϊκό και παγκόσμιο πλαίσιο έχει πληγεί η εμπιστοσύνη των Ελλήνων απέναντι στην δημοκρατία και στον ρόλο που θα πρέπει να διαδραματίζει η πολιτική. Είχα επίσης τονίσει πως παρόλη την απογοήτευση ο δρόμος για την ελληνική πολιτεία είναι ένας. Ο δύσκολός δρόμος που θα μας κρατά μέσα στην ευρωπαϊκή οικογένεια και θα μας δώσει τις προϋποθέσεις να αναπτύξουμε το ελληνικό καπιταλιστικό σύστημα προωθώντας τις επενδύσεις, την επιχειρηματικότητα και την ιδιωτική πρωτοβουλία. Είναι όμως γεγονός πως οι κύριες αιτίες, η ουσία του ελληνικού προβλήματος, βρίσκεται πέρα από την οικονομική αποτελεσματικότητα. Η ελληνική χρηματοοικονομική κρίση έχει μια πολιτική πλευρά η οποία δεν μπορεί να παραβλεφθεί και η οποία είναι τελείως διαφορετική από τα άλλα ευρωπαϊκά κράτη. Αυτό είναι

Τα Βαθύτερα Αίτια της Ελληνικής Οικονομικής Κρίσης

To άρθρο αυτό έχει αρχικά δημοσιευτεί στο Sklias, P. and Maris, G. (2013) The Political Dimension of the Greek Financial Crisis, Perspectives on European Politics and Society, vol. 14, no. 1, pp. 144-164.  Το λίνκ του άρθρου είναι το  http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/15705854.2012.732392#.Uz_p4Kh_uSo  Για να αναφέρετε αυτό το άρθρο στη βιβλιογραφία σας παρακαλώ χρησιμοποιείστε είτε την παραπάνω αναφορά είτε το  Σκλιάς, Π., Ρουκανάς, Σ. και Μαρής, Γ. (2012) Η Πολιτική των Διεθνών και Ευρωπαϊκών Οικονομικών Σχέσεων, Εκδόσεις Παπαζήση, Αθήνα. καθώς αυτό ειναι το 9ο κεφάλαιο του βιβλίου. Τα Βαθύτερα Αίτια της Ελληνικής Οικονομικής Κρίσης 1. Εισαγωγή Πρόσφατα πολλοί ερευνητές προσπάθησαν να αναλύσουν τις βασικές αιτίες της ελληνικής οικονομικής κρίσης. Στην πλειοψηφία αυτών των αναλύσεων τους, εστίασαν σε μια σειρά από οικονομικούς συντελεστές, οι οποίοι τονίστηκαν ως τα βασικά αίτια του προβλήματος. Πιο συγκεκριμένα, θεωρήθηκε πως τα υψηλά δημόσια ελλείμματα, η